By Günther Schulze and Bambang Suharnoko Sjahrir
Indonesian districts spend excessively on their own administration —
money that could be spent on delivering public services for the people.
The key problem is that democratic accountability is not (yet)
sufficiently effective. After the 2001 decentralisation the districts,
the third tier of government after center and provinces, are responsible
for the provision of basic services such as health, education, and
infrastructure and spend around a third of the consolidated government
budget. They are therefore important providers of public goods and services, especially for the poor.
On average around 30 per cent of district budgets are absorbed by
expenses for district administration, of which 85 per cent go to general
government administration and the rest to other administrative
functions, such as development planning, unity and local politics, or
people and village empowerment (but not to sector administrations such
as health or school administrations). This level is excessive by all
international standards: administrative spending is double the
districts’ average allocation for infrastructure (15 per cent) and the
second-biggest budget item after education (34 per cent).
These high levels of administrative spending are persistent: even
though Indonesia’s district budgets doubled between 2001–07, and have
steeply increased thereafter, the share of administrative spending has
declined only slightly since 2005. In absolute terms administrative
spending per capita has sharply increased, which is remarkable since
many spending items in this category have a strong fixed cost component.
For instance, the expenditures for bupatis’ (regent) offices or for travel expenditures should increase only slightly with rising budget levels.
What explains these persistently excessive levels of administrative spending?
A recent study
analyses this issue using data for 399 districts over the time period
2001–09. One line of explanation could be the emergence of new districts
(pemekaran) and the need to establish new administrations. Yet,
the evidence shows that the splitting of districts is not the reason for
high spending levels. Newly created districts do not spend more per
capita on administration during the start-up phase, only the composition
of administrative expenditure is different. New districts have a higher
share of capital expenditure and a lower share of staff expenditure as
they still have to build up physical infrastructure and hire personnel.
A prime explanation is bureaucratic self-interest and a lack of
accountability. Bureaucrats and local politicians profit from larger
offices — both literally and in terms of the number of people employed —
and from bigger budgets as they provide more convenience and more
possibilities to employ family members or to accommodate the wishes of
key allies and constituencies. This is true for all bureaus of the
district government, but since a district’s central bureau is
politically more powerful than the others it has better opportunities to
lobby for big budgets and thus a greater propensity towards wasteful
spending.
This administrative overspending is a wasteful activity as it directs
funds away from the provision of public services towards uses that
benefit the bureaucrats and politicians in power, but not the people. As
such it constitutes a form of ‘legal corruption’ (the World Bank
defines corruption as ‘misuse of public office for private gain’). Such
waste can be avoided if governments are held accountable.
Decentralisation in Indonesia
in 2001 replaced bureaucratic accountability to the central government
with democratic accountability to the local electorate. If democratic
accountability works at the local level, increasing democratisation
should rein in the excessive administrative spending.
Two distinct steps towards more democratisation have taken place in
Indonesia: the elections of district heads by the democratically elected
local parliaments, and subsequently the direct elections of district
heads by the local electorate. The incumbent district heads that had
been appointed under Suharto were allowed to serve their full terms,
which came to an end at different points in time. As a consequence, both
steps took place at different times across the districts, making it
easy to identify the increase in democratic circumstances. The study
uses this circumstance to analyse whether democratisation has any impact
on the size of administrative spending.Unfortunately, both
democratisation steps did little to reduce the misallocation of
resources.
Local party composition influences the extent of administrative
overspending. In the sample of districts that did not split, for which
the study has consistent data on local parliaments’ compositions, it
finds that in districts with high political concentration or a dominant
party, administrative overspending was even larger. In other words,
political competition reduces the degree of waste.
These findings show that district governments are still not
sufficiently accountable to the local constituency. Greater
accountability would rein in excessive spending on themselves for the
benefit of the people they are obliged to serve.
As such, decentralisation and democratisation at the local level are
alone not sufficient for eliminating wasteful administration
expenditure. Reform that improves political competition, including by
increasing the transparency of the political process and making it easy
for outsiders to run for office, is likely to be essential. Sensible
next steps should include abolishing all barriers to entry for
candidates to run for office of district head. This may lead to higher
competitiveness of the political process, more freedom to choose, and
thus better outcomes.
Dr. Günther G. Schulze is Professor of Economics at the Department of Economics, University of Freiburg, Germany.
Bambang Suharnoko Sjahrir is is a PhD student in the same department and works for the World Bank in Indonesia.
This article originally appeared 18 April 2014 on the East Asia Forum.
No comments:
Post a Comment